Читаем Kicking Away the Ladder. Development Strategy in Historical Perspective полностью

Third, exports from the colonies that competed with British products were banned. We have already mentioned that the cotton textile industry of India was dealt a heavy blow in the eighteenth century by the British ban on cotton textile imports from India (‘calicoes’), even when the latter’s products were superior to the British ones (see section 2.2.1 above).[210] Another example of this came in 1699, when Britain banned the export of woollen cloth from its colonies to other countries (the Wool Act), essentially destroying the Irish woollen industry. This Act also stifled the emergence of the woollen manufacturing industry in the American colonies.[211] In yet another example, a law was introduced in 1732, which mainly targeted the beaver-skin hat industry that had grown up in America; this law banned the exports of hats from colonies either to foreign countries or to other colonies.[212]

Fourth, the use of tariffs by colonial authorities was banned or, if they were considered necessary for revenue reasons, countered in a number of ways. When in 1859 the British colonial government in India imposed small import duties on textile goods (between three and ten per cent) for purely fiscal reasons, the local producers were taxed to the same extent in order to provide a ‘level playing field’.[213] Even with this ‘compensation’, the British cotton manufacturers put constant pressure on the government for the repeal of the duties, which they finally obtained in 1882.[214] In the 1890s, when the colonial government in India once again tried to impose tariffs on cotton products – this time in order to protect the Indian cotton industry, rather than for revenue reasons – the cotton textile pressure groups thwarted the attempt. Until 1917, there was no tariff on cotton goods imports into India.[215]

<p>2.3.2. Semi-Independent Countries</p>

Outside the formal colonies, the British (and other NDCs’) attempts to impede the development of manufacturing in less developed countries mainly took the form of imposing free trade through so-called ‘unequal treaties’ during the nineteenth century. These treaties normally involved the imposition of tariff ceilings, typically at the five per cent flat rate, and the deprivation of tariff autonomy.[216]

It is extremely disconcerting to note that the binding of tariffs at a low, uniform rate (although not necessarily below five per cent) is exactly what modern-day free-trade economists recommend to developing countries. The classic work by Little et al. argues that the appropriate level of protection is at most 20 per cent for the poorest countries and virtually zero for the more advanced developing countries. World Bank argues that ‘[e]vidence suggests the merits of phasing out quantitative restrictions rapidly, and reducing tariffs to reasonably low and uniform levels, such as a range of 15-25 percent [emphasis added].[217]

Britain first used unequal treaties in Latin America, starting with Brazil in 1810, as the countries in the continent acquired political independence. Starting with the Nanking Treaty (1842), which followed the Opium War (1839-42), China was forced to sign a series of unequal treaties over the next couple of decades. These eventually resulted in a complete loss of tariff autonomy and, symbolically, a Briton being the head of customs for 55 years, from 1863 to 1908. From 1824 onwards, Siam (now Thailand) signed various unequal treaties, ending with the most comprehensive one in 1855. Persia signed unequal treaties in 1836 and 1857, as did the Ottoman Empire in 1838 and 1861.[218]

Even Japan lost its tariff autonomy following the unequal treaties signed after its opening up in 1854 (see section 2.2.7 above). It was eventually able to end the unequal treaties, but that did not happen until 1911[219] In this context, it is also interesting to note that when Japan forcefully opened up Korea in 1876 it exactly imitated the Western countries, forcing Korea to sign an unequal treaty that deprived the latter of its tariff autonomy despite the fact that Japan itself still did not have tariff autonomy itself.

The larger Latin American countries were able to regain tariff autonomy from the 1880s, before Japan did. Many others regained it only after the First World War, but Turkey had to wait for tariff autonomy until 1923 (despite the unequal treaty having been signed as early as 1838!) and China until 1929.[220] Amsden shows how industrialization in these countries was only able to begin in earnest when they regained their tariff (and other policy) autonomy.[221]

<p>2.3.3. Competitor Nations</p>
Перейти на страницу:

Похожие книги

100 знаменитых катастроф
100 знаменитых катастроф

Хорошо читать о наводнениях и лавинах, землетрясениях, извержениях вулканов, смерчах и цунами, сидя дома в удобном кресле, на территории, где земля никогда не дрожала и не уходила из-под ног, вдали от рушащихся гор и опасных рек. При этом скупые цифры статистики – «число жертв природных катастроф составляет за последние 100 лет 16 тысяч ежегодно», – остаются просто абстрактными цифрами. Ждать, пока наступят чрезвычайные ситуации, чтобы потом в борьбе с ними убедиться лишь в одном – слишком поздно, – вот стиль современной жизни. Пример тому – цунами 2004 года, превратившее райское побережье юго-восточной Азии в «морг под открытым небом». Помимо того, что природа приготовила человечеству немало смертельных ловушек, человек и сам, двигая прогресс, роет себе яму. Не удовлетворяясь природными ядами, ученые синтезировали еще 7 миллионов искусственных. Мегаполисы, выделяющие в атмосферу загрязняющие вещества, взрывы, аварии, кораблекрушения, пожары, катастрофы в воздухе, многочисленные болезни – плата за человеческую недальновидность.Достоверные рассказы о 100 самых известных в мире катастрофах, которые вы найдете в этой книге, не только потрясают своей трагичностью, но и заставляют задуматься над тем, как уберечься от слепой стихии и избежать непредсказуемых последствий технической революции, чтобы слова французского ученого Ламарка, написанные им два столетия назад: «Назначение человека как бы заключается в том, чтобы уничтожить свой род, предварительно сделав земной шар непригодным для обитания», – остались лишь словами.

Александр Павлович Ильченко , Валентина Марковна Скляренко , Геннадий Владиславович Щербак , Оксана Юрьевна Очкурова , Ольга Ярополковна Исаенко

Публицистика / История / Энциклопедии / Образование и наука / Словари и Энциклопедии