Because of oil and gas, a positive trade balance has been characteristic of the post-Soviet period. Every year, the country has exported an average of 10 per cent more than it has imported, and over eighteen years that gives more than 200 per cent of cumulative growth. But, strangely, domestic assets – state-owned and private – have hardly grown. The reason is the flight of capital. 39 The offshore wealth of Russian officials,
Why did the ‘liberal’ governments of the 1990s and 2000s do so little to redistribute the income from oil and gas to benefit the population and the environment of their country? Their logic reproduced not the liberal but the mercantilist tradition. The export of raw materials, the restraint on domestic consumption, the growth of gold reserves and the enrichment of the trusted elite – these are mercantilist policies. Their theoretical grounds can be found in Britain’s ‘old colonial theory’ of the eighteenth century. The speeches of the most influential of post-Soviet economists, Yegor Gaidar, articulated his deep mistrust of the Russian population – unqualified, unproductive and, in a word, indolent. In contrast, he hoped that investing in the elite – boosting the salaries of bureaucrats and judges or letting new oligarchs grow their capital – would stop corruption and improve the quality of management. In this world view, the people weren’t ready for reform but the elite was, and petrodollars were distributed according to readiness.
When the price of oil increases, the value of labour decreases. Discontent grows, but the oilmen don’t strike; the political ideas from the era of coal do not work in the era of oil. The rich become richer, the poor poorer, the elite dumber. New social theories compare modern life to a fossil resource but do not suggest how to change it. Zygmunt Bauman’s idea of ‘liquid modernity’ plays with the oily idea of liquidity. The actor-network theory of Bruno Latour results in diagrams that resemble gas pipelines. Having stabilised and subsidised neoliberal states throughout the world, oil has, eventually, been excluded from their privatisation policies: selling other businesses, they have not touched the oil sector. On the contrary, in the 2000s a new wave of nationalisation swept through Venezuela, Bolivia, Ecuador and Russia, bringing oil-extracting companies under state control. Huge price fluctuations enriched some speculators, impoverished others and boosted the financialisation of the market. Inequality of all sorts – between countries, classes, genders and cohorts – increased even further.